Connect with us

Technology

Governments better at regulating ‘sharing economy,’ Uber, scooters

Published

on


UberMikeDotta/Shutterstock

  • For years, city and state governments around the
    country have been fighting over “sharing economy”
    issues.
  • Now those fights are making more sense.
  • Companies and lawmakers have learned to speak the same
    language, and they’re finding compromises.

This is a column about government working better.

For years, city and state governments around the country have
been fighting over “sharing economy” issues. What’s changing is
those fights are making more sense.

These are no longer so often fights between companies that think
they’re entitled to be unregulated and governments that want to
ban businesses they find new and suspicious.

Companies and lawmakers have learned to speak the same language,
have climbed down from extreme positions, and are doing better at
finding compromises that harness the benefits of business
innovation while limiting unintended costs imposed on
communities.

They’re not getting it right all the time, and there’s a lot of
work left to be done, especially around labor regulation for
people who work in these industries. But they’re getting it right
more often, and even when they get it wrong — as New York
may have recently done with new
rules on Uber and Lyft
— they’re showing more flexibility,
emphasizing that rules are subject to change as we see how they
work.

The scooter freak out did not lead to scooter bans

A few months ago, there was a spate of articles about how
everyone hates electric scooters, which
had become ubiquitous in cities like San Francisco. They’re
blocking the sidewalk. They’re getting thrown in San Francisco
Bay. People are riding them on the sidewalk. They are an
offensive symbol of tech bro culture. Etcetera.

There were calls from ornery residents: Get these off the
streets. This sentiment
was sometimes expressed in human excrement.

But scooters, while perhaps annoying, are useful. They address a
very real “last mile” problem: Will people use transit if the
place they’re going is a 12-minute walk from the subway? What if
it’s a four-minute scooter ride from the subway instead?

Instead of banning, several cities have taken a smarter approach:
Require operators to get licenses, impose rules about how to use
a scooter safely and nicely, and limit the number of scooters in
operation so there aren’t piles of unused scooters littering the
sidewalks.

San Francisco did order all the scooters off the streets
temporarily, but a limited number are coming back this month for
a yearlong pilot.

Santa Monica has imposed an especially
sensible, flexible scooter cap: If a company’s scooters are
getting a lot of use, it can put more on the street. If they
aren’t getting used very much, they have to take them off.

Cities and companies understand regulation should be a work in
progress

Instead of bans, jurisdictions have been channeling their
skepticism and concerns about sharing businesses in more useful
directions: Pilot projects, temporary caps, and regulations of
fixed duration.

Seattle, the US city with the largest dockless bike share
presence, has treated its programs as an explicit pilot. A big
pilot: Three companies have 10,000 bikes operating in Seattle,
about the same number as New York’s dock-based Citi Bike program.

For a year, Seattle collected data and surveyed users and
residents. Now, the three pilot companies are continuing to
operate as the city decides what kind of permanent regime it
wants — having learned
a number of valuable lessons about bike parking
along the
way.

In New York, the city council has just passed new regulations on
app-based ride share services, to much fanfare and also much
objection.

The rules pause the issuance of new registrations for cars that
may be dispatched by apps — there are currently about 80,000 of
them, or more than five times the number of yellow cabs in the
city. But that’s only for a year, as the city tries its hand at
regulations to guarantee drivers a minimum wage and discourage
Uber cars from cruising midtown Manhattan without passengers.

Mayor Bill de Blasio sought a cap on rideshare cars four years
ago and got smacked down by a city council responding to angry
drivers. The new rules have been greeted in some corners as de
Blasio’s revenge. But the number of rideshare cars operating now
is drastically higher than in 2014, and this isn’t a fight about
whether Uber will cease to be a major part of the transportation
landscape in New York — it’s a question on the margin about
numbers and fares and driver earnings.

It’s also a question about traffic speeds. Lawmakers cite the
growth in rideshare cars as a reason traffic speeds in Manhattan
have fallen in recent years. A congestion charge for all cars
would probably be a better way to address this than a regulation
specific to ride-sharing, but that’s not on the table, because a
congestion charge would require state legislative approval.

Ian Adams, who studies sharing economy rules for the libertarian
R Street Institute think tank, is skeptical that rideshare-only
congestion regulations would be effective at speeding up traffic.
But he did praise the city for keeping the license cap to only
one year, to then be reevaluated after study.

“I think that expresses some level of skepticism they have
internally about this approach,” he said, regarding the city
council. “It may harm their own constituents and I think they’re
aware of that as well, and they’re reluctant to do something that
will irretrievably destroy the system. That said, I think there’s
a reason we haven’t seen other large cities go this way.”

There are still big questions to resolve

Some disputes about the sharing economy are harder to compromise
on than questions about how much or how many of something should
be available in a city.

Happy compromises have been harder to find on short-term home
rental services like Airbnb than on ride-sharing services like
Uber. This reflects bigger, substantive policy concerns about
home sharing than other kinds of sharing.

Homeowners have valid quality-of-life concerns about the
apartment buildings they live in turning into hotels —
concerns that will not always be addressed by landlords and
building managers if the government does not step in. And the
diversion of housing units to the short-term rental market can
undermine rent-control policies in cities like New York and San
Francisco.

Labor rules in the sharing economy also require a lot of work.

Uber calls its drivers “driver-partners” even though what they do
looks a lot like being an employee without the legal protections
that come from a payroll-employee relationship. California’s
Supreme Court agrees, and has ordered companies like Uber and
Lyft to start treating drivers as employees, eligible for
overtime and minimum wage and other benefits of employment.

The companies complain, with varying degrees of plausibility,
that requiring them to treat their workers as employees will have
negative consequences for consumers and even the workers
themselves.

The companies may have a point about overtime rules: These exist
to protect employees from being required to work extra-long hours
without extra-high pay. But since ride-sharing drivers set their
own hours, do they need that protection? Will requiring
time-and-a-half for overtime increase drivers’ earnings, or will
it just lead companies to order them to stop driving after eight
hours — reducing their earnings and forcing them to choose a
work schedule they didn’t want?

I don’t think the answer is obvious. It would be interesting to
see how an experiment with time-and-a-half rules for ridesharing
works out in some jurisdiction.

On the other hand, it’s hard to see a good argument for why
sharing-economy workers should be exempt from the minimum wage
like they are today.

Yes, a minimum-wage requirement might make some jobs
uneconomical, and some people might be told not to work at all
because the company isn’t willing to pay the wage required. But
that’s also true of the minimum wage in the regular payroll
economy, and we view that as an acceptable trade-off for the way
the minimum wage boosts low-wage workers’ income overall.

In the long run, resolving these issues may require something the
economists Seth Harris and Alan Krueger have proposed:
A third kind of employment classification,
less than payroll
employment but more than independent contracting, that is
customized to the kinds of flexible work arrangements that
characterize the sharing economy.

But it would be good to see the results of more local experiments
before designing a national form of those rules. After all,
states and localities seem to be getting better at conducting
these sorts of experiments.

Continue Reading
Advertisement Find your dream job

Trending